The London School of Economics and Political Science
November 2012
How did American and British policymakers become so enamored with
free markets, deregulation, and limited government? Based on archival
research and interviews with leading participants in the movement, Masters of the Universe traces
the ascendancy of neoliberalism from the academy of interwar Europe to
supremacy under Reagan and Thatcher and in the decades since. Paul Kelly finds that the various pieces of the puzzle do not quite fit together into a single picture.
Masters of the Universe: Hayek, Friedman, and the Birth of Neoliberal Politics. Daniel Stedman Jones. Princeton. September 2012.
Daniel Stedman Jones’s new book is yet another contribution to the
academic reckoning of the global financial crisis. What is distinctive
about it is that he provides an analysis and critique of the dominant
language of political economy of the last four decades – neoliberalism.
Or at least I think that is what he is doing.
The book begins with a survey of the major intellectual sources of
neoliberalism, namely Friedrich Hayek and Milton Friedman, although Karl
Popper is also mentioned and so, perhaps curiously, is the Freiberg
School in post war Germany. The argument turns from the intellectual
sources to the growth and dissemination of neoliberal ideas whilst
Keynsianism dominated policy making in western democracies. This is
followed by an overview of the political crises that led to the rise of
neoliberal inspired politicians such as Reagan and Thatcher although the
turn to monetarist and supply-side policy-making is also credited to
the Carter and Callaghan administrations in the US and the UK. Two case
studies of the politics of policy transfer complete the argument which
concludes with a short polemical argument linking neoliberalism to the
global financial crash. So we have intellectual history for the
political theorists, policy-transfer for the political scientists, some
political economy for the political economists and the economic
historians and polemic for the politically engaged: in effect something
for everyone. Although the book is not without merit, and I enjoyed part
of the journey, in the end it is overambitious and sadly fails to
deliver on its promise.
Although deeply interested in the subject matter and sympathetic to
the view that ideas matter, I was disappointed that more attention was
not devoted to developing the fundamental thesis. There is an
interesting story about the development of opposition to Keynesianism
and how this opposition positioned itself to take advantage of the
collapse of the Bretton Woods settlement in the early 1970s. Hayek is
certainly part of the story and so is Friedman but their relationship is
very complex. In the early chapters we get some discussion of the
climate of opposition that Hayek was able to exploit in the US and the
mention of important figures in the development of the Chicago School.
Yet the connections between the various thinkers are ambiguous,
fortuitous or at best under explained. Another problem is that the later
identification of thinkers as neoliberal tends to colour the story too
much. Much of Friedman’s radicalism is obscured by the company he was
later to keep and the way in which his ideas were used. The same could
be said of Hayek or the Freiberg School (who disappear from the story as
we focus on Reagan and Thatcher and their epigones). So when we get to
the final conclusion that suggests that the banking collapse and
subsequent bailouts undermines the neoliberal policy agenda we are left
with a curious non-sequitur. Defenders of Hayek like defenders of Keynes
tend to argue that they have been ill-served by their friends and far
from being refuted by experience they have yet to be tried: an argument
well made by Stephanie Flanders in a recent television series.
A second and related issue is precisely whether the neoliberals were
or are, right or wrong? There is much to be said for and against Hayek,
Friedman and Keynes but the arguments are complex and difficult to
address as part of such a broad agenda. What the book never makes clear
is whether the neo-liberals were right – except for the brief and
polemical conclusion. Yet at times the argument does seem to assess the
arguments. Arguably the conclusion provides a curious vindication for
Hayek in that the attempt to have the benefits of unfettered markets
without the prospect of failure was always to misunderstand what Hayek
intended. There is a partial attempt to examine whether Freidman is
right about Keynes, but at other times we are left with the view that
ideas are merely epiphenomenal and what is driving policy change are
deeper political and economic forces or luck. But this makes the need
for an expanded account of policy change and of intellectual biography
all the greater. The book repeats the importance of individuals such as
the Butler brothers – Stuart and Eamon – but they seem to pop-up out of
nowhere and then shape the world. Were the Butlers lucky cranks or
visionary policy entrepreneurs or both? Did Hayek and Friedman convert
them or did they merely provide the intellectual armory for ideological
positions they were inclined to hold anyway. The various pieces of the
puzzle do not quite fit together into a single picture.
Finally the book is ill served by assuming a polemical concept as an
ideological unity. Neoliberalism works as a concept only so far as we do
not expect too much of it. Like all such concepts once we probe too
deeply it melts into the air. What it leaves behind, and what the book
at least identifies, are some interesting and complex questions about
the interplay between ideas, institutions and luck in shaping politics.
In the end I was left with a feeling similar to Marx’s in reading
Feuerbach on religion. We cannot merely undo the iniquities of the world
around us by trying to un-think the ideas of our predecessors.
Paul Kelly is Professor of Political Theory at the
London School of Economics and Political Science. He joined the LSE in
1995 after teaching for five years at the University of Wales, Swansea.
Prior to that he held a visiting research fellowship at the University
of Chicago Law School and at the Bentham Project, University College
London. He graduated from York University with a First in Philosophy and
an MA in Political Theory. His PhD is from the University of London,
where he spent two years at LSE and a further year at UCL. He is
currently editor of the Journal Utilitas. Professor Kelly’s
research focuses on: British political theory from the Seventeenth
century to the present, especially the political philosophies of John
Locke, Jeremy Bentham and John Stuart Mill, Liberal Political
Philosophy, especially the work of Ronald Dworkin and Brian Barry,
Multiculturalism, group rights and national identity, equality of
outcomes and equality of opportunity and theories of social justice. Read reviews by Paul.
No comments:
Post a Comment